Le 5 extra
27 pages
English

Le 5 extra

-

Le téléchargement nécessite un accès à la bibliothèque YouScribe
Tout savoir sur nos offres
27 pages
English
Le téléchargement nécessite un accès à la bibliothèque YouScribe
Tout savoir sur nos offres

Description

1 Le 5. Extra uppgifter från Halliday Fundamentals of physics: 8.7; 8.21; 8.31; 8.35; 8.53; 8.59; 8.75; 8.121 eller Principles of Physics: 8.7; 8.23; 8.29; 8.37; 8.55; 8.57; 8.69; 8.77 8.7. Fig.8-34 shows a thin rod of length L=2.00 m and negligible mass, that can pivot about one end to rotate in a vertical circle. A ball of mass m=5.00 kg is attached to the other end.
  • initial speed
  • work by a spring force
  • kinetic energy of the system
  • cord
  • rest
  • spring
  • point
  • mass
  • potential energy
  • block

Sujets

Informations

Publié par
Nombre de lectures 18
Langue English

Extrait

Advances in Management & Applied Economics, vol.1, no.3, 2011, 31-57
ISSN: 1792-7544 (print version), 1792-7552 (online)
International Scientific Press, 2011

Nonlinear Integer Programming Transportation
Models:
An Alternative Solution
1 2,* 3 4Chin Wei Yang , Hui Wen Cheng , Tony R. Johns and Ken Hung


Abstract
The combinatorial nature of integer programming is inevitable even after taking
specific model structure into consideration. This is the root problem in
implementing large-scale nonlinear integer programming models regardless of
which algorithm one chooses to use. Consequently, we suggest that the size of
origin-destination be moderate. In the case of large origin-destination problems,
more information on the size of x is needed to drastically reduce the ij
dimensionality problem. For instance, if x is to be greater than the threshold ij
value to be eligible for the rate break, computation time can be noticeably
reduced. In the case of large right-hand-side constraints, we suggest scaling these

1 Department of Economics, Clarion University of Pennsylvania, Clarion PA 16214,
USA, and Department of Economics, National Chung Cheng University, Chia-Yi,
Taiwan, R.O.C., e-mail: yang@clarion.edu
2 Department of International Business, Ming Chuan University, Taipei, Taiwan, R.O.C.,
e-mail: hwcheng@mail.mcu.edu.tw
* Corresponding Author
3 Department of Administrative Science, Clarion University of Pennsylvania, Clarion PA
16214, USA, e-mail: johns@clarion.edu
4 Sanchez School of Business, Texas A&M International University, Laredo, Texas
78041, USA, e-mail: hungkuen@gmail.com

Article Info: Received : December 8, 2011. Published online : December 30, 2011 32 Nonlinear Integer Programming Transportation Models

values to the nearest thousands or millions. The approach from Excel proposed in
this paper is particularly appropriate if one can balance the sizes of origin-
destination and right-hand-side constraints in such a way that computation time is
not excessive. For a large-scale problem, one must exploit the structure of the
model and acquire more information on the bounds of discrete variables. Our
approach certainly provides an alternative way to solve nonlinear integer
programming models with virtually all kinds of algebraic functions even for
laymen who do not feel comfortable with mathematic programming jargons.

JEL classification numbers: C61
Keywords: Logistics/Distribution, Mathematical Programming


1 Introduction
Spatial interaction models have received a great deal of attention either in
theoretical advances or empirical applications. In the early 1940's, spatial
allocation problems were cast in the form of the linear programming
transportation models (LPT) developed by Hitchcock [24], Kantorovich [30] and
Koopmans [33]. The original works by Hitchcock [24] was published in
mathematical physics as was that by Kantorovich [30]. The Koopmans’ work was
indeed the first on transportation modeling in economics [33]. And more recently
Arsham and Khan [1] offered an alternative algorithm to the stepping stone
method. Enke [11] laid the foundation of the spatial equilibrium model based on
the Kirchhoff law of electrical circuits. Samuelson's influential work [59] on
spatial price equilibrium (SPE) has generated a significant amount of interest in
the spatial economics. In 1964, Takayama and Judge [64] reformulated the Enke-
Samuelson problem into a quadratic programming model with the objective of Chin-Wei Yang, Tony R. Johns, Hui Wen Cheng and Ken Hung 33

maximizing "net social payoff." Since then, theoretical advances and refinements
along the line of the Enke, Samuelson, Takayama and Judge abound.
There has been a large body of literature that improves on or extends the
original Takayama-Judge model, including: reformulation and a new algorithm by
Liew and Shim [44]; inclusion of income by Thore [66]; transshipment and
location selection problem by Tobin and Friesz [67]; sensitivity analyses by Yang
and Labys [76], Dafermos and Nagurney [7]; computational comparison by
Meister, Chen and Heady [47]; iterative methods by Irwin and Yang [27]; a linear
complementarity formulation by Takayama and Uri [65]; sensitivity analysis of
complementarity problems by Yang and Labys [77]; applications of the linear
complementarity model by Kennedy [32]; a solution condition by Smith [61]; the
spatial equilibrium problem with flow dependent demand and supply by Smith
and Friesz [62]; nonlinear complementarity models by Irwin and Yang [28] and
Rutherford [57]; variational inequalities by Harker [19]; a path dependent spatial
equilibrium model by Harker [20]; and dispersed spatial equilibrium by Harker
[21]. In addition, the SPE model has become increasingly fused with other types
of spatial models. For instance, the solutions of a SPE model can be obtained and
combined with the gravity model (Harker [21]) and the commodity or passenger
flows can also be estimated using econometric (e.g., the logit model, Levin [38]).
Furthermore, the spatial modeling of energy commodity markets has often
involved various extensions beyond the basic SPE approach (e.g., Kennedy [32],
Yang and Labys [77] and Nagurney [52]). These extensions include linear
complementarity programming, entropy maximization, or network flow models.
For the detailed description of the advances in the spatial equilibrium models,
readers are referred to Labys and Yang [35]. Computational algorithm was
developed by Nagurney [51]; applications and statistical sensitivity analysis by
Yang and Labys [76]; mathematical sensitivity analysis by Irwin and Yang ([27],
[28]); spatial equilibrium model with transshipment by Tobin and Friesz [67];
applications of linear complementarity problem by Takayama and Uri [65] and 34 Nonlinear Integer Programming Transportation Models

Yang and Labys [77], Beyond that imperfect spatial competitions include works
by Yang [73]; variational inequality by Dafermos and Nagurney [7], iterative
approach by Nagurney [51]; dispersed spatial equilibrium model by Harker [21];
spatial diffusion model by Yang [74]; spatial pricing in oligopolistic competition
by Sheppard et al. [60]; and the spatial tax incidence by Yang and Page [78]. The
advances and applications of the spatial equilibrium model can be found in Labys
and Yang ([35] and [36]).
In particular, the spatial price equilibrium (SPE) has much richer policy
implementations since each region has a price sensitive demand and a supply
function. The linear programming transportation (LPT) model, on the other hand,
has fixed demand and capacity constraints and as such lacks policy implications
(Henderson [23]). The SPE model, in contrast, has been widely implemented both
in theoretical advances and in empirical applications. Applications of SPE models
include a wide range of agricultural, energy and mineral commodity markets as
well as international trade and other spatial problems, readers are referred to the
works by Labys and Yang [35]. Advances in computer architecture (parallel
processing) have led to large scale computations in spatial equilibrium commodity
and network models (Nagurney [51], Nagurney et al. [53]) and in spatial
oligopolistic market problems (Nagurney [52]), spatial Cournot competition
model by Yang et al. [75]. Most recent application on SPE can be found in lumber
trade in North America by Stennes and Wilson [63]. In addition, the SPE model
has become increasingly fused with other types of spatial models. For instance, the
solutions of a SPE model can be obtained and combined with the gravity model
(Harker [21]) and the commodity or passenger flows can also be estimated using
econometric (e.g., the logit model, Levin [38]). Furthermore, the spatical modeling
of energy commodity markets has often involved various extensions beyond the
basic SPE approach (e.g., Kennedy [32], Yang and Labys [76] and Nagurney [52]).
These extensions include linear complementarity programming, entropy
maximization, or network flow models. It is interesting to note that the large-scale Chin-Wei Yang, Tony R. Johns, Hui Wen Cheng and Ken Hung 35

Leontief-Strout was published one year before Takayama and Judge reformulated
the Enke-Samuelson problem into a standard quadratic programming or spatial
equilibrium model. The entropy modeling had not received enough attention until
1970 when Wilson derived the gravity model from the entropy-maximizing
paradigm. By the middle of the 1970's Wilson and Senior [72] proved the
5relationship between the linear programming and the entropy-maximizing model .
As a matter of fact, Hitchcock-Kantorovich-Koopmans linear programming
transportation problem was shown to be a special case of the entropy model. The
detailed descriptions on these models may be found in Batten and Boyce [2] and
the combinatorial calculus by Lewis and Papadimitriou [39]. However, the
implementation of such entrop

  • Univers Univers
  • Ebooks Ebooks
  • Livres audio Livres audio
  • Presse Presse
  • Podcasts Podcasts
  • BD BD
  • Documents Documents